Chapter VI : Externalities of biomass based electricity production compared to power generation from coal in the Netherlands

 

Co-authors: Berry Meuleman, Wim Turkenburg, Ad van Wijk, Ausilio Bauen, Frank Rosillo-Calle, David Hall.

Accepted for publication in 'Biomass and Bioenergy'.

 

Abstract - Externalities of electricity production from biomass and coal are investigated and compared for the Dutch context. Effects on economic activity and employment are investigated with help of Input/Output and multiplier tables. Valuations of damage from emissions to air are based on generic data from other studies. In addition external costs are estimated for nitrogen leaching and for the use of agrochemicals for energy crop production.

The average private costs for biomass and coal based power generation are projected to be 68 and 38 mECU/kWh respectively in the year 2005. It is assumed that biomass production takes place on fallow land. Coal mining is excluded from the analysis. If the quantified external damages and benefits are included the cost range for bio-electricity is 53-70 mECU/kWh and 45-72 mECU/kWh for coal.

Indirect economic effects (increment of Gross Domestic Product) and the difference in CO2 emissions are the most important distinguishing factors between coal and biomass in economic terms. Damage costs of other emissions to air (NOx, SO2, dust and CO) are of the same order of magnitude for both coal and biomass (coal mining excluded). In this analysis environmental impacts of energy farming are compared mainly to fallow land focused on the use of fertilizers and agrochemicals. The related damage costs appear to be low but should be considered as a preliminary estimate only.

The quantitative outcomes should not be considered as the external costs of the two fuel cycles studied. Many impacts have not been valued and large uncertainties persist e.g. with respect to the costs of climate change and numerous dose response relations. More detailed analysis is desired with respect to macro-economic impacts. The results serve as a first indication, but the outcomes plead for the support of bio-electricity production and/or taxation of coal based power generation.

 

1. INTRODUCTION

Integrated bio-energy systems which rely on specifically produced energy crops are at present not competitive with fossil fuel based energy systems. The situation might change in the somewhat longer term, as a result of the further development and improvement of energy crops, conversion technology and integrated production systems.

Nevertheless, the use of biomass from energy crops to fulfil our energy needs could already now offer several advantages compared to the consumption of fossil fuels. Biomass is a renewable energy source with zero or low net carbon dioxide emissions when the biomass is produced in a sustainable way. Furthermore, the SO2 emissions could be low because of the inherently low sulphur content of biomass. In addition, biomass could be an alternative crop for farmers in Europe and the USA, where the agricultural sector produces large food surpluses and where arable land is being set-aside. This land can be used to grow energy crops. Consequently, biomass can be an employment generator, especially in rural areas where additional employment is often desired. Biomass would also be an indigenous energy source for most countries; this may improve the reliability of the energy supply and result in additional economic benefits if it replaces the import of fossil fuels. Finally the growth of crops to produce energy can have environmental impacts. These impacts could be negative (compared to fallow land) but also positive if e.g. the growth of SRC (Short Rotation Coppice) or perennial grasses to produce energy would replace the production of food crops.19,21,44,63 However, the use of biomass to produce energy can also have negative effects, like the emission of pollutants and increase in road transport. Those are all effects of bio-energy production that are not accounted for in the calculation of the private costs of bio-energy use: externalities. A market externality occurs when some costs (or benefits) of a market transaction are borne (or received) by parties not directly involved in the transaction. Externalities, therefore, represent costs or values that are not directly reflected in the market pricing. Accounting for the expected beneficial overall effects of bio-energy could improve its competitiveness with fossil fuels.

One of the first attempts to value the external effects of energy consumption was made by Hohmeyer in 1988.24 To determine the external costs of environmental emissions, he applied a top down approach. Starting from estimates of the total damage done to the environment and human health by air pollutants,59 he calculated the damage done by an energy source by determining the contribution of that source to the air pollution. This work was updated in 1991.25 Hohmeyer's study was criticized amongst others because his investigation was based on relatively old estimates of damage caused by environmental emissions. It was also criticized because it did not focus on the marginal effects of those emissions or take into account the current levels of pollution from other sources and the non-linearity of many dose-response curves.

Since 1988 many other studies on the external effects of energy consumption have been done. An extensive follow-up of these studies is currently being undertaken by the Fuel Cycle Studies of the USA and EC.4,34 In these studies the so-called Damage Function Approach (DFA) is followed in order to investigate the impact of a number of fuel cycles on the environment. DFA can be characterized as a bottom-up approach. It starts by determining the increment in emission levels due to a new activity (e.g. a fuel cycle), then goes on to assess physical impacts (health effects, damage to crops, etc.) followed by an economic valuation of these impacts. This leads to damage estimates of the marginal effects. Drawbacks to this approach are that the results are often strongly site specific and rely on numerous dose-response curves. Therefore, the approach is very data intensive.4,34 Due to the lack of data often only a part of the actual external effects can be valued. Consequently, the uncertainty in the outcomes could be considerable. As a result the reliability of external cost evaluations and the way they should be used in policy making is heavily debated.23,54,57

Various methods have been developed for pricing external effects. An overview is given by Pearce et al.40 A brief summary has been made Munasinghe.64 One approach is to look at the impact of environmental changes on directly observable behaviour valued in conventional markets (mitigation costs of damage; loss of output due to sickness or death; loss of production, etc.). Another approach is to calculate the replacement costs of a shadow project to offset the environmental damage. A third set of methods uses indirect or surrogate market data to determine the value (willingness to pay for bottled water; willingness to pay for travel to nature areas; wage premium to compensate for hazardous circumstances, etc.). A final group of methods simulates market-like behaviour, using marketing experiment or surveys to determine the value. An example is contingent valuation: the willingness to pay for an environmental asset or to accept compensation for its loss, each determined by direct questions.40,64

Pearce et al. do not advocate any method. The best choice depends on the specific case, desired reliability and availability of data. However, Munasinghe indicates that direct market data are preferable to indirect market data and especially data obtained from simulated market behaviour. Other authors argue that the contingent valuation method (CVM) should be restricted to specific applications23 and should not be used to value uncertain, non-visible, long-term effects such as climate change or loss of biodiversity.57

A specific method for valuing the costs of environmental emissions is the abatement costs approach. In this approach the cost of avoiding certain emissions is calculated. An example is the cost of sulphur removal at coal plants which then serves as a measure of the external costs of SO2 emissions. The main advantage of this approach is its pragmatic character and relatively exact results. Another benefit is that it allows for least cost planning e.g. for utilities. For a more detailed discussion, see van Wijk et al.60 However, a major drawback of taking abatement costs as a basis for external cost evaluations is that the results have no relation to the actual damage done to human health and the environment.

In the literature on externalities, bioenergy fuel cycles have received fairly limited attention, especially with respect to socio-economic effects. Ribera et al.45, the National Technical University of Athens36 and Oak Ridge National Laboratory38 (the latter is still ongoing42) have performed studies on the externalities of biomass. The external effects studied cover the economic impact of emissions to air, nitrogen leaching, erosion, employment, damage to roads and occupational risks.

In this article we will study the direct costs and the externalities of electricity production from biomass and from coal in the Netherlands. In this study we consider not only environmental effects, but also socio-economic effects (employment and indirect economic impacts) In this study the term 'externalities' is used in a broad sense; not only for environmental externalities but also for, indirect, socio-economic effects. This is useful since the potential advantages of renewable energy options and bioenergy in particular also relate to employment and economic issues. These issues need to be included to achieve a fair comparison between fuel cycles. The comparison between the two fuel cycles is of interest since it may provide insight into the actual net costs or benefits of implementing bio-energy compared with a main alternative. This could influence policies directed towards a shift from fossil fuels use to the use of renewable energy sources.

The analysis of the the biomass and the coal fuel cycle will focus on a national scale. The functional unit for comparing the systems will be one kWh. The focus on an evaluation of the external costs on a national scale is based on the notion that the outcomes could be especially meaningful for policy-making by governmental bodies. Decision-making at national level is at present a likely way for internalizing external effects in the costs of energy. Furthermore, a variety of (potential) external effects are location specific. In the case of decision making with regard to energy supply in the future, the indirect consequences for the national economy can be a crucial factor. These consequences can be a justification for applying governmental incentives such as taxes or subsidies. It should be noted that the environmental impact of coal mining will not be included in our analysis since coal mining has ceased in the Netherlands. However, the socio-economic effects of importing coal will be taken into account.

One reason for focusing on coal for comparison is that the bio-energy system studied is expected to operate in baseload power generation, just like coal fired power plants in the Netherlands. Another reason is that an important argument for realising biomass based power generation in the Netherlands is the reduction of CO2 emissions. Replacement of coal based power generation can substantially contribute to this objective.

Relevant impacts that may lead to external/indirect costs or benefits which will be considered here are: emissions to air (NOx, SO2, dust, CO) result in impacts on nature, human health and the built environment. Emissions of CO2 may contribute to climate change. Energy crop production may result in emissions to water and soil. Also impacts on water-use, landscape and biodiversity are anticipated. In both fuel cycles expenditures on investments, fuel, operation and maintenance lead to indirect economic effects, both on the GDP and with respect to employment generation.

However, at the present moment it is impossible to value all the external effects of fuel cycles. For example, issues like loss of nature and changes in biodiversity, depletion of resources and energy security are hard to value in financial figures. Nevertheless, although there are problems and uncertainties, economic valuation of environmental damages and socio-economic effects is useful since it visualizes, at least partly, what the economic impact of a (new) activity could be. Since the economic attractiveness of a given project is generally a major criterion in decision making, economic valuation of external effects is important, which is why this valuation is carried out in this study.

In this article we begin by briefly discussing the external effects that will be investigated and the methods that will be applied to value these effects in monetary terms. This is done in section 2. The core of the paper deals with the application of these methods in order to investigate and compare the external costs and benefits of power generation from indigenously produced biomass and from imported coal. Section 3 describes the systems considered. Section 4 goes into the actual valuation of the externalities. The meaning and usefulness of the results will be discussed in section 5. Finally we will draw some draw some conclusions from this exercise.

 

2. EFFECTS OF THE FUEL CYCLES AND VALUATION METHODS USED

The fuel cycles we want to investigate in this article - electricity production from biomass and from coal in the Netherlands - involve numerous, (potential) external effects. Here we describe which effects will be investigated and which method will be used to value these effects.

Table 1 gives an overview; the first column of the table lists the possible indirect socio-economic effects and environmental external effects of the fuel cycles. The second column briefly summarizes the possible valuation methods of the external effects. Also the main characteristics, advantages and disadvantages are given. The third column mentions which valuation method will be applied in this study and why. Because the methods are at different stages of development, lack of data and because the effects considered are so different, more than one method is needed to value all the effects mentioned.

Table 1. Overview of potential external effects of biomass fuel cycles, methods for valuing these effects and selection of the valuation approach adopted in this study.

 Indirect socio-economic effects

Methods and characteristics

Selected for this study

Direct and indirect economic effects on GDP.

1/ Calculation of multiplier effects by means of I/O tables of the (national) economy and determining the effects of expenditures related to the fuel cycle.

2/ Advanced dynamic economic models.

Analyis of multiplier effects by means of I/O tables. Applying dynamic models would require extensive and highly detailed data which is beyond the scope of this study.

Direct and indirect employment effects.

Analysis of direct employment by means of labour requirements of the fuel cycle. Indirect effects can be estimated by taking multiplier effects in the (national) economy into account (I/O tables).

Analyis of multiplier effects by means of I/O tables; valuation of employment by means of unemployment subsidies saved.

Energy security and diversification.

The economic effects of energy supply disruptions and price fluctuations and sometimes also the costs of military operations can provide a basis for valuation.

No valuation in this study. Valuation is doubtful, as well as the allocation of the costs to a specific fuel cycle.

Occupational risks and risks of increased traffic.

Assessment of safety risks related the fuel cycle (loss of life, injuries). Economic valuation is strongly influenced by the selected figure for the value of human life.

No valuation in this study; occupation risks may be considered as 'non-externality' due to compensation in wages.

Environmental effects

 

Emissions to air (NOx, SO2, dust, CO, etc.); impacts on human health, flora, fauna, buildings.

1/ Damage Function Approach: Starts from a given activity (e.g. power plant) and calculates dispersion of contaminants and additional effects on the environment. Valuation on the basis of physical effects (loss of agricultural production, mortality, damage to buildings, etc.)

Results give marginal effects and are site specific. Non-linear dose-reponse curves can be used. Data intensive method.

2/ Top down approach: Starts from estimation of the (economic) damage to the environment and human health from environmental pollution in general. The contribution of various sources to total emissions is the basis for allocation of external costs to these sources. Results give average effects, are only to a limited extent site-specific and often assume linear dose-response relations. Approach is however relatively simple to apply.

3/ Abatement costs approach: the external costs of environmental emissions is set equal to the abatement costs of those emissions. Transparent method, but main disadvantage is that there is no relation to actual (economic) damage.

Valuation using generic data from other studies representative for the Dutch context. Results from both bottom up as Damage Function Approach are used in order allow comparison between the results. Focus lies on damages on a national scale.

 

 

 Environmental effects

Methods and characteristics

Selected for this study

Emission of greenhouse gases; impacts on climate.

1/ Valuation by means of expected damages through climate change (loss of land, migration, increased risks of heavy storms, etc.) Valuation of economic effects of climate change very difficult due to large uncertainties in expected effects and inclusion of interest rates.

2/ Valuation by means of abatement costs. Main disadvantage is that there is no relation to actual damage.

Cost range as given in literature will be included in this study.

Emission of fertilizers (or other contaminating compounds); impacts on nature and human health.

1/ Damage function like approach: dispersion modelling of leaching fertilizers. Difficulties arise when allocating effects to energy farming activities and when valuing those effects.

2/ Willingness To Pay data with respect to water quality.

3/ Abatement costs to meet water quality standards. No relation to actual damage.

Since allocation of any effect to human health or nature from nitrogen leaching will involve large uncertainties and arbitrary choices, WTP data will be used in this study.

Emission of agrochemicals; impacts on nature and human health.

1/ Similar to emission of fertilizers; however the number of potential dose-response curves is far larger due to complexity of (possible) effects.

2/ By estimating a shadow price through estimating the loss in (agricultural) production when fewer or no chemicals are used. Projected production losses are then the basis for determining the shadow price. It is then implicitly assumed that 'optimal' decisions are made in policy on the desired level of emission reduction. The marginal abatement costs (in this case production losses) are then equal to the marginal damage costs.

DFA by using dispersion models and dose response curves is not possible because there is a lack of insight into many aspects. Therefore a shadow price will be used for the Dutch context. This approach assumes an 'optimal' policy with respect to the desired emission reductions.

Hydrological effects; impacts on groundwater table and evapotranspiration.

Valuation not demonstrated so far. Quantifying physical effects of woody energy crops and perennial grasses with respect to water consumption partly difficult due to lack of practical experience. Effects also highly site specific (soil, local climate, groundwater tables and availability).

Hydrological aspects are not valued in this study due to limited data with respect to physical effects.

Effects on soil quality and erosion (relevant for biomass production).

Soil quality aspects are difficult to value in economic terms. No methods developed so far.

Erosion can be valued in terms of loss of productivity of agricultural land. Detailed knowledge about erosion of energy crops is lacking, although compared to numerous food crops SRC and perennial grasses may result in low to negligible erosion.

Neither aspect is valued in this study. Erosion is hardly a problem in the Dutch context. Physical effects on soil quality hard to determine and therefore also hard to valuate. With regard to both aspects, however, certain benefits are expected for woody crops because of good ground cover and increasing organic content of soils and possibly prevention of diseases.

Effects on nature and biodiversity.

Methods to valuate biodiversity and species are under development. Results are highly uncertain and site and context specific.

Not valued in this study, especially because actual effects of energy farming on nature and biodiversity are to a large extent unknown. Certain benefits however are expected.

 

In this study special attention is given to indirect socio-economic effects of the fuel cycles, in particular effects on the Gross Domestic Product and employment, as these effects may be of major importance for the competitiveness of the fuel cycles. We will try to determine the effects, using Input/Output modelling. This approach allows the quantification of multiplier effects, both on GDP and on the generation of employment.

The Damage Function Approach (DFA) can be followed for the cost evaluation of emissions to air. It is however beyond the scope of this work to perform detailed dispersion modelling or to provide total damage estimates of these emissions. Therefore, we apply generic data determined with a DFA for the Dutch context. For comparison we will do the same with generic data that stem from Hohmeyer. Using two sources with a basically different approach enables a comparison to be made between the two outcomes. The results and comparison will be discussed in detail in chapter 4.

A valuation attempt will be made for two other effects related specifically to energy farming: nitrogen leaching due to the use of fertilizers and environmental impacts due to the use of agrochemicals. However, on these subjects DFA-studies have not yet been performed. For nitrogen leaching it is unclear to what extent leaching in a certain area actually contributes to exceeding standards e.g. for groundwater quality. Effects of fertilizer use for the production of energy crops are dependent on specific conditions and even if these are known determining physical effects can be problematic. We therefore adopt Willingness To Pay (WTP) data with regard to the desire of people to have access to clean groundwater in order to determine the costs of nitrogen leaching. To value the environmental impact of agrochemical use, a shadow-price is calculated based on the reduced agricultural production when fewer or no agrochemicals are used. Both nitrogen leaching and agrochemical use are included in this analysis to obtain a feeling for the order of magnitude of possible damage caused by energy farming. However, on forehand it is recognized that further research on this subject is desired.

For the Dutch context further effects on soil quality, erosion, hydrology, nature and biodiversity due to biomass production for energy are too uncertain to assess, since the actual impacts of energy farming are hardly known yet. From experience in other countries, however, we expect that in the case of SRC Willow (minor) benefits are achieved compared to growing conventional food crops.

 

3. PERFORMANCE AND EFFECTS OF THE FUEL CYCLES

3.1 Background information

The Netherlands is a densily populated country with high pressure on available space. Agriculture is very intensive and has both the highest yields and highest fertilizer and pesticide use per hectare in the world.13 Farmers recieve a relatively high income, also per hectare compared to other (European) countries. Since the high cost of land and labour will result in relatively high biomass energy costs, it will be difficult for biomass to compete with other energy sources, especially cheap natural gas. Indeed commercial crop production for energy purposes is currently not competitive with fossil fuels.31

The availability of land to produce biomass for energy purposes in the Netherlands is discussed elsewhere in a study by Faaij et al.16 It is concluded that, despite the demand for land for a number of other functions, a significant amount of land may come available for energy farming provided that energy farming is an economically viable activity for farmers. Land could become available because of a decrease in land use for growing food crops and dairy farming due to expected productivity increments. The total amount of land available for energy crops taking into account other land demanding functions like urban and nature development, could lie between 110,000 and 250,000 ha in the year 2015. In this study we assume that energy farming takes place on fallow land.

Currently there is no commercial energy farming in the Netherlands. Therefore, to investigate its costs and benefits projections have to be used with respect to the performance, yield and costs of biomass production systems in the Dutch context. The potential of energy crop production and the conversion of biomass energy to electricity are discussed below, assuming a time frame of about 5-10 years.

3.2 Selection and performance of the bio-energy system

The conversion unit of the selected bio-energy system is assumed to be a 30 MWe Atmospheric Circulating Fluidized Bed gasifier coupled to a General Electric LM 2500 gas turbine and equipped with conventional low temperature gas cleaning and a flue gas dryer using waste heat. The projected performance of this system is discussed in Faaij et al.14 and Consonni et al.9 The efficiency is expected to be about 42% (LHV; using clean wood with 50% moisture). Investment costs are expected to be in the range 1000-2300 ECU/kWe; the lower value is expected to represent the situation of a fully proven commercial plant. O&M costs are considered to be about 2.1 MECU/year.14

Short Rotation Coppice (SRC) Willow is selected as the energy crop. A considerable amount of experience has been gained with this crop in energy production in Sweden. Willow is suited for most Dutch conditions and shows a favourable energy ratio (energy input:energy output = 1:10-15).31 Projections for the yield of willow production have been published in the literature. Estimates vary from 8 to 15 tonnes dry matter per hectare per year.31,35,63 The yield depends on the e.g. soil type, production system and crop variety. An average yield of 12 odt/ha/yr is considered obtainable within 5-10 years. Such a yield is based on crops harvested at intervals of 3 years and a plantation lifetime of about 24 years. Other rotation schemes are however possible (2 to 5 year rotations). At the present stage it is not fully known what production system is best in economic terms.

Biomass is to be transported from the fields to the conversion unit. Optimal logistics are a complex matter and for accurate analysis detailed data of the production area and the road network are required.3 Here a simple approach will be adopted:

It is assumed that biomass will be transported by road. Willow is harvested and transferred to trucks (25 tonnes load) at the side of the production fields and transported directly to the conversion facility. Central, covered storage at the conversion facility is assumed. The conversion unit is assumed to be located in the centre of an area where energy farming takes place. In this study we assume that about 10 to 30% of the land around the plant will be used for energy farming. Also we assume that the chips are used in a power plant with load factor of 80%. On the basis of these assumptions, we can calculate the total number of hectares required (9400 ha), the average transport distance (7.1-12.2 km), and total number of transport kilometres required per year (127,000-220,000 km including return distance). For simplicity, dry matter losses during storage are not taken into account. Such losses can be minimized by covered storage and, partial, storage in the form of sticks.3 Data regarding the cost and energy use of biomass transportation are given in Feenstra et al.17

3.3 Cost of electricity produced by the bioenergy system compared to coal based power generation

On the basis of these assumptions we have calculated the overall production cost per kWh for the entire system. Some details of these calculations and the results are presented in table 2. Major variables influencing the Cost Of Electricity (COE) are the farmers' income, the investment cost of the conversion unit and the applicable subsidies. Other important parameters are the crop yield and the energy conversion efficiency.

In our study three cases for crop production have been determined with subsidy levels between 0 and 700 ECU per ha/yr. Details of the economic aspects of SRC Willow production under Dutch conditions are discussed in Rijk.46 The selected cases represent likely situations in the near future.

An interest rate of 3% is applied to all related investments and cash flows; this is the rate which is applicable at the moment in the agricultural sector.46 With respect to investments for the conversion unit a depreciation period of 25 years and an interest rate of 5% are assumed. The resulting COE from biomass ranges between 4.0 and 10.5 ECUct/kWh. The lowest value may be obtained in the longer term (e.g. 10-15 years), the highest value represents the current situation assuming that BIG/CC technology has been demonstrated commercially.

For further calculations we use the 'average' case described in table 2: in this case investment costs for the power plant are assumed to be relatively high (i.e. 2000 ECU/kWe): furthermore, the fallow land subsidy of 500 ECU/ha.yr is assumed to be still available, since we consider the production of biomass on fallow land to be feasible. This case results in a COE of 6.8 ECUct/kWh.

For comparison, the COE of coal based power generation in the Dutch context is (projected to be) 3.8 ECUct/kWh (those costs are obtained with a load factor of 70%).2,49,55 Despite possible changes in technology such as IG/CC instead of combustion, those COE are not expected to drop much. The world market coal price is expected to remain stable for long periods. The projected direct costs of bio-electricity are therefore expected to be roughly twice the COE produced from coal.

3.4 Emissions to air of the two fuel cycles

The emissions to air from crop production, harvesting and transport are calculated by using generic data for diesel engines and multiplication by the total energy use for both transport and crop production operations. Total emissions from the biomass conversion unit are calculated from the total fuel gas flow and projected emission levels.14 The use of trucks will also result in emissions of NOx, SO2, dust and CO and hydrocarbons. In this

study the emission factors for trucks are derived from Perlack et al.41 Results and relevant details are given in table 3. The expected emissions for coal based power generation with modern power plants that will be in operation 5-10 years from now are given in the last column. These emissions are based on pulverized coal combustion plants equipped with extensive flue gas cleaning.18,61 Also, the emission data for coal based power generation in an Integrated Gasification/Combined Cycle, a likely future coal conversion technology, are given.

 

Table 2. Overall cost performance of the selected bio-energy system consisting of a 30 MWe BIG/CC power plant fired with SRC Willow for average, mimimum and maximum cost cases.

 

average

min

max

 

Crop production

 

 

 

 

farmers' income

610

480

610

ECU/ha/yr

fuel costs

70

36

133

ECU/odt

subsidy levela

502

700

0

ECU/ha/yr

total farmers' income

5.7

4.5

5.7

MECU/yr

total subsidy paid

4.7

6.6

0

MECU/yr

Total fuel costs

7.9

4.1

15.0

MECU/yr

Logistics

 

 

 

 

land cover energy crops

20

30

10

%

average transport distance

8.6

7.1

12.2

km/ton one way

total transport distance by trucks

156,000

127,000

220,000

km/year TWO way

total costs of transport

0.08

0.06

0.11

MECU/yr

total costs of transfer & storage

0.07

0.07

0.07

MECU/yr

Total cost of logistics

0.15

0.13

0.18

MECU/yr

Conversion

 

 

 

 

total power production

210

210

210

GWh/year

fuel input

225,000

225,000

225,000

wet tonne/year

investment costs

2000

1000

2300

ECU/kW

total investment costs

60

30

69

MECU

depreciation costs

4.3

2.1

4.9

MECU/yr

O & M

2.1

2.1

2.1

ECU/yr

Costs per kWhb

0.068

0.040

0.105

ECU/kWh

aSubsidy levels are based on fallow land subsidy (set-aside) which is paid annually for agricultural land not used for food crop production (502 ECU/ha.yr) and on forestry subsidies paid in the Netherlands to stimulate forestation (700 ECU/ha.yr). All cost figures related to crop production stem from Rijk.46

bGeneral assumptions on the operation of the system and general economic parameters: Discount rate: 5% (conversion). Lifetime of the plant: 25 years. Capacity of electricity production plant: 30 MWe (electricity only). Conversion efficiency: 42% (LHV basis). Load factor: 80% (7000 hours/year). Fuel data: 50% moisture content as delivered at plant; Lower Heating Value: 8 GJ/wet tonne. Costs of road transport: 0.04 ECU/tonne.km for 25 tonne trucks. Costs of transfer: 0.29 ECU/wet ton (one operation)17

 

Table 3. Annual emissions to the air due to crop production, logistics and conversion to electricity for a 30 MWe BIG/CC power plant generating 210 GWh per year. In addition, the emission per kWh is presented for both the bio-energy and coal fuel cycle.

 

Biomass conversiona

(tonne/year)

Crop productionb

(tonne/year)

Logisticsc

(tonne/year)

Total emissions

(tonne/year)

Biomass fuel cycle (g/kWh)

Coal conversion (g/kWh)d

SO2

15

5

0.13

20

0.10

0.38

NOx

45

56

1.3

103

0.49

0.28

dust

6

6

0.05

12

0.06

0.05

CO

61

56

1.3

118

0.56

-

HC

-

12

0.34

13

0.06

-

CO2

(fossil fuel)

-

4,505

425

4,930

24

815

aEmissions to air of a 30 MWe BIG/CC unit based on Atmospheric Circulating Fluidised Bed technology and low temperature gas cleaning. Emission levels: SO2 10 mg/Nm3, NOx 30 mg/Nm3, CO 40 mg/Nm3, dust 4 mg/Nm3, flue gas flow: 60 Nm3/sec. Uncertainties with respect to emissions occur at drying and storage. However closed systems can be applied (e.g. steam drying and closed storage). Therefore a minor contribution to the total emissions is expected from those operations.14,15 Total emissions for 80% load factor.

bEmission factors for diesel usage in agricultural machinery are applied.41 A total average annual energy consumption of 6 GJ/ha is assumed.63 Total annual emissions from crop production operations are calculated for the selected 30 MWe power plant with 42% efficiency at baseload power, which requires 225 ktonne wet fuel per year.

cEmission factors for biomass transport derived from Perlack et al.41 and expressed in factors per amount of energy (diesel) consumed: SO2: 0.09 g/MJ, NOx: 0.99 g/MJ, dust 0.104: g/MJ, CO: 0.99 g/MJ, HC: 0.22 g/MJ, CO2: 80 g/MJ. Total emissions represent the annual supply of 225 kton of wet wood per year to fuel the power plant. These emissions represent the average cost case with a total number of transport kilometres of 156.000 (two way, so including empty trucks). Emissions for both empty and loaded trucks are assumed to be the same. Energy use for (biomass) transport is derived from Feenstra et al.17: 0.48 MJ/tonne.km (or 12 MJ per 25 tonne.km), transfer requires 3.1 MJ/Nm3 or 0.47 MJ/wet tonne.

20% land cover for energy crops around the conversion plant is assumed.

d Emissions from coal conversion represent a modern pulverized coal plant with 44% efficiency.55,61 Emissions of CIG/CC (Coal Integrated Gasification/Combined Cycle) are 0.64 g NOx/kWh, 0.14-0.23 g SO2/kWh, 0.007g dust/kWh and 798g CO2/kWh.

 

4. VALUATION OF EXTERNAL EFFECTS

4.1 Effects on the Gross Domestic Product (GDP)

Investments in the bio-energy system and in the coal system result in expenditures in various sectors of the (national) economy during the lifetime of the plant. These expenditures will affect other economic sectors as well and will result in an increase in economic activity apart from the operation of the fuel cycle as such. This effect is called the multiplier effect.

In this study we are interested in the difference between the multiplier effects of the two systems. The difference can be seen as a net economic benefit of the option that results in the highest indirect increment of GDP. As indicated in section 2, we will calculate the multiplier effect by making use of input-output tables for the Netherlands economy and describe the interlinks between the expenditures in various sectors.5,6

First the direct expenditures by the coal and biomass fuel cycles are estimated. The expenditures related to the biomass energy system are extracted from studies which describe energy farming of willow and biomass gasification for electricity production.14,46,56 This breakdown of expenditures and the allocation over various sectors are described in detail in a background report of this analysis.15 The expenditures of the coal energy system are based on the costs of operating a modern 600 MWe coal-fired power plant.2,55,62 These expenditures are attributed to appropriate economic sectors as taken up in the input/output table. The expenditures for biomass fuel production, and for the operation and maintenance and investment costs of both fuel cycles is assumed to take place within the Dutch economy. Only the expenditures for coal are expected to take place outside the Dutch economy, since coal is imported into the Netherlands.

Biomass production is assumed to take place on fallow land for which a fallow land subsidy of 502 ECU/ha.yr is currently available.46 The subsidy will be given to farmers in both the biomass and the coal case. The subsidy itself is however not included in the expenditures, also not in the biomass case. In the case of the coal fuel cycle, the agricultural land is assumed to be fallow and no other economic activities take place on this area of land.

The annual average final demands of the two cycles under study are calculated for discount rates of 0, 3, and 10%. To determine the production increments, the annual average final demand is calculated with the Leontieff inversion of the I/O table (The Leontieff inversion is described as D X=(I-A)-1 D Y, in which D Y=(Y1-Y0) represents the increment in final demand and D X=(X1-X0) the increment in final production. I is the unit matrix and A is the technical coefficients matrix.). The calculated production increments include direct and indirect effects. The indirect production increments are calculated by subtracting the annual average final demand of the total production increment including the mulitplier effect. The change in GDP is the sum of the change in value added and value added tax of the Dutch economy. To calculate these two parameters we applied a function obtained by linear regression analyses performed on figures for the production, value added and value added tax for the period 1985 to 1994. Table 4 presents an overview of the production, intermediary use, value added and value added tax for the Netherlands in the period 1985-1994.5,6

We assume that the relation between production and value added will remain constant in the time-frame used in this analysis. As a first order approach this seems reasonable since a linear function is obtained for the period 1985-1994 as well. The indirect effects are calculated for an ideal context in which production capacity and labour are under-utilized. If economic activity is already high, inflatory effects may occur, such as increasing costs of labour and goods. Howeverm we assume that, considering the size of the projects, this will not directly lead to increased inflation and that production capacity is available in relevant economic sectors.

Table 5 summarizes the calculated indirect production increments for three discount rates in kECU for the biomass and coal fuel cycle. One should bear in mind that the biomass plant is a 30 MWe unit (210 GWh/year) and the coal plant a 600 MWe unit (3600 GWh/year). By adding up the calculated value added and the value added tax, we know the change in GDP that will result from the implementation of the projects. A crucial assumption in the calculation of changes in GDP for the coal fuel cycle is the contribution of the costs of coal to the GDP. It is assumed that the expenditures for purchasing coal (at world market prices) takes place outside the national economy, and therefore contributes negatively to the value added of the economy (This is directly explained by the definition of GDP which is the sum of consumption, investments, expenditures of the government and exports minus imports.28)

 

Table 4. The production, intermediary use, added value and value added tax for the Netherlands in the period 1985 to 1994. Also included are the characteristics for the regression functions that give the relation between production and value added value added tax.

 Year

Production

Intermediary use

Value Added

Value Added Tax

(Billion Dfl)a

(Billion Dfl)a

(Billion Dfl)

(Billion Dfl)

1985

820

434

387

33

1990

949

479

470

40

1992

1,027

513

514

43

1993

1,037

509

528

42

1994

1,084

530

555

43

Characteristics of regression functionb

 

Value Added

Value Added Tax

Regression output constant

-135.000

-500

X Coefficient

0.64

0.041

correlation coefficient

0.99

0.98

 a1 ECU = 2.15 Dfl,- (1995)

bFor value added, the best fitted function is the following linear function:

Value Added (MDfl) = 0.64 * production increment (MDfl) -135.000

For value added tax, the best fitted function is the following linear function:

Value Added Tax (MDfl) = 0.041 * production increment (MDfl) - 500

 

Because the expenditures for the biomass fuel cycle are considerably higher per kWh produced than for electricity production from coal it is logical that a higher indirect economic effect is calculated simply because of those higher expenditures. A correction is therefore made for the difference in the Costs Of Electricity (COE) from biomass and from coal (see note table 5). The net indirect effect of biomass based on this correction is shown in table 5. The biomass fuel cycle results in a GDP increment of 6-15 mECU/kWh, but the coal fuel cycle results in a negative increment between 7 and 8.4 mECU/kWh. This mainly due to the fact that coal imports contribute negatively to the GDP.

In the description of the energy crop production (see section 3) subsidies were mentioned that could apply to SRC. Currently subsidies are paid for setting land aside. These set-aside subsidies serve as income support to farmers and help prevent the production of surplus food crops. Those subsidies can be considered as an expenditure that will be made, regardless whether non-food crops are produced or not. Therefore, those subsidies have not been added to the costs of the bio-energy system and are not included when the multiplier effect is calculated.

 

Table 5. Changes in added value, costs of fuel import, value added tax and GDP caused by total expenditures (annualized per year) for both the biomass and coal fuel cycle as a function of the interest rate.

 

Biomass fuel cycle (MECU)b

Coal (MECU)c

Interest rate

0%

3%

10%

0%

3%

10%

Value Added

2.95

2.08

1.18

19.7

17.2

14.6

Fuel Importa

-

-

-

-45.8

-45.8

-45.8

Value Added Tax

0.19

0.14

0.08

1.3

1.1

0.9

GDP

3.15

2.22

1.25

-24.8

-27.5

-30.3

 

 

GDP increment including correction for higher COEbiomass (mECU/kWh)d

15.0

10.6

6.0

-6.9

-7.6

-8.4

 aCoal price = 1.34 ECU/GJ49

bBiomass plant: 30 MWe; 210 GWh/yr

cCoal plant: 600 MWe; 3600 GWh/yr

dAssuming that e.g. the national government is responsible for financing additional power generation capacity, such a body would have to spend a factor (COEbiomass-COEcoal)/COEbiomass (6.8-3.8)/6.8 = 0.44 more on biomass than on coal to produce the same amount of electricity. The net indirect economic effect of the expenditures for the biomass fuel cycle is then: (1-0.44) * gross indirect effect. The figures mentioned have been corrected with this factor.

 

4.2 Employment

 Effects on employment can be divided in direct employment, caused by the operation and construction of the power plants and fuel production, and indirect employment, generated in other sectors of the economy because of the expenditures that result from the implementation of the fuel cycle in question.

 Direct labour requirements of the biomass fuel cycle consist of the sum of labour requirements for crop production, construction, operation and maintenance of the conversion plant and for transportation of the biomass. For the coal fuel cycle the direct labour requirement concern the conversion (construction, operation and maintenance) and inland transport of coal.

An overall labour input of 7.5 man hours per ha per year for SRC Willow production is given in Rijk46. Defining a man year as 1700 working hours, the annual direct labour requirement for the defined system is 41.4 man years. The selected conversion system requires annually approximately 19 man years for base load operation (although the degree of automation is a crucial factor in this respect; more details are given in Faaij et al.14). Logistics is considered to be solely road transport. Transfer is considered to be part of the crop production system and unloading will take place at a central storage facility at the conversion plant. The annual amount of labour for biomass transport is estimated to be 4 man years. The labour requirements of the construction of a 20 MWe plant are estimated to be 225 workers over a period of two years.30 This leads to 13.5 job-equivalents per year when extrapolated to a 30 MWe plant with a lifetime of 25 years (see table 6) (This may be an overestimation, but since the investment costs of the BIG/CC unit considered are assumed to be relatively high (i.e. 2000 ECU/kWe) a relatively high labour input may be expected.). For the coal fuel cycle in the Netherlands the direct labour requirements are calculated at 384 jobs for a 600 MWe coal fired power plant.11

A method of assessing the indirect employment effects is to use employment multipliers which can be derived from input-output and employment tables. The Netherlands Bureau of Statistics calculated these employment multipliers for the year 1990 for 41 sectors. (The employment multipliers are given in direct, indirect and cumulated labour intensity. The direct labour intensity is the direct input on labour (in man-years) per currency unit final demand. The cumulative labour intensity is the indirect input on labour (in man-years) per currency unit final demand.)

 

Table 6. Direct employment of the biomass and the coal fuel cycle.

  

Job equivalents/year

Activity

Biomass fuel cycle (30 MWe)a

Coal (conversion; 600 MWe)b

construction

14

276

fuel production

42

N.A.

logistics

4

N.A.

conversion

19

108

Total

79

384

man year per MWe installed

2.6

0.64

man year per GWh

0.37

0.107

 aSources: Rijk46 and Faaij et al.14

bConstruction: 76.7 man year/TWh; O&M: 30 man year/TWh11

 

On the basis of these figures we calculate the changes in indirect employment. Details are given in the background report.15 Table 7 gives the increase in indirect employment for the biomass and coal fuel cycle for three discount rates.( A range of discount rates was used for the calculation of the annual average final demand (section 4.1). This final demand serves as a direct input for the employment tables and therefore the interest rate affects the total calculated indirect employment. This is inherent to the approach followed here.)

Biomass obviously has a significantly higher labour intensity than coal, the difference being approximately a factor 2.6 per GWh produced. This can be explained partly by the fact that bioenergy production is more expensive. Moreover, coal mining is not included here since coal is imported into the Netherlands.

Economic valuation of employment is a rather arbitrary matter. In this study it is assumed that employment generated by the projects will always reduce the number of long term unemployed persons in the Netherlands (either directly or indirectly). The economic benefits are expressed in terms of unemployment benefits saved. These vary between 156 to 631 ECU/month, depending on various factors. Combining these figures with the employment generated results in a benefit of 0.83 to 4.04 mECU/kWh for the biomass fuel cycle (including the correction for the higher COE of biomass) and of 0.32 to 1.50 mECU/kWh for the coal fuel cycle. In these outcomes the variation through the applied range in interest rates is included.

 

Table 7. Overview of the direct and indirect employment generated by the biomass and coal fuel cycle.

  Employment generated

 

Biomass fuel cyclea

 

Coal (conversion)b

 

discount rate

direct employment

indirect employment

Totals

direct employment

indirect employment

Totals

man year/year

0%

79

34

113

384

327

711

 

3%

79

24

103

384

281

665

 

10%

79

14

93

384

224

608

man-year/GWh

0%

0.37

0.16

0.53

0.11

0.09

0.20

 

3%

0.37

0.12

0.49

0.11

0.08

0.19

 

10%

0.37

0.07

0.44

0.11

0.07

0.17

 aResults for the biomass fuel cycle for a 30 MWe plant producing 210 GWh/year.

bResults for coal based power generation for a 600 MWe plant producing 3600 GWh/year.

 

The value of employment might however change in the future. In case unemployment is low an increased demand for labour might result in an upward pressure on wages, which may reduce employment in other sectors. In the current situation, however, employment generation is considered desirable and we assume that this will not change dramatically in the time frame considered in this study.

 4.3 Emissions to air

 Generic data from other externality studies are used to estimate the damage costs that result from various emissions to air. The results are summarised for both biomass and coal in table 8. Cost figures per unit of emitted contaminant (like NOx, SO2) from both top down (Hohmeyer24,26) and bottom up (Dorland et al.11) studies are applied. Data from Hohmeyer apply to the German context but are considered reasonably representative for the Netherlands as well. Data from Dorland et al.11 are determined specifically for the Dutch context. They generated those data for a modern pulverized coal fired power plant with extensive gas cleaning in the vicinity of Amsterdam. In order to translate the results of these studies to the two cases in this exercise, the emissions to air per kWh caused by the biomass fuel cycle and the coal fuel cycle (see table 3) are combined with the derived cost data per weight unit of emission. Then the damage per emission per kWh produced for both fuel cycles is calculated. Full details are given in the background report.15 The main results of this exercise are given in table 8 for SO2, NOx and dust emissions.

Although the two approaches of Hohmeyer and Dorland et al. are very different in methodological terms, the numerical results are rather similar. It should be noted however that the two studies take different damage categories into account. The study by Dorland et al. focuses on effects to human health and excludes effects on flora and fauna. Chronic health effects play a minor role in the valuation of Hohmeyer (which can be considered as an omission). Dorland et al. give lower estimates for damage to materials (such as buildings). The focus on SO2 in Dorland et al. and that the Hohmeyer data are based on damage in the German context, which are assumed to be higher per average building than in the Netherlands, are explanations.12 The two studies are therefore difficult to compare; both merely give an illustration of quantifiable external costs. They also illustrate that the uncertainties in the overall outcomes of these studies are substantial.

 

Table 8. Summary of the damage costs of emissions to air based on generic data from Hohmeyer25,27 and Dorland et al.11.

  

 

Hohmeyer data

ExternE data

 

 

Biomass fuel cycle (mECU/kWh)b

Coal (conversion)

(mECU/kWh)a

Biomass fuel cycle

(mECU/kWh)b

Coal (conversion)

(mECU/kWh)a

 

 

min

max

min

max

min

max

min

max

Flora

SO2

0.06

0.09

0.24

0.24

 

 

 

 

 

NOx

0.39

0.58

0.22

0.33

Not evaluated in this study

 

dust

0.04

0.04

0.03

0.03

 

 

 

 

 

Total

0.49

0.72

0.49

0.72

 

 

 

 

Fauna

 

Damage costs are negligible compared to other damages

Not evaluated in this study

Human health

SO2

0.02

0.42

0.06

1.60

 

 

 

 

 

NOx

0.10

2.57

0.06

1.47

 

 

 

 

 

dust

0.01

0.17

0.01

0.13

 

 

 

 

 

mortality acute

 

 

 

 

0.39

0.89

0.29

0.67

 

mortality chronic

 

 

 

 

1.75

5.19

1.31

3.87

 

morbidity

 

 

 

 

0.09

0.26

0.07

0.19

 

Total

0.12

3.17

0.13

3.20

2.24

6.34

1.67

4.73

Materials

SO2

0.02

0.04

0.09

0.15

0.02

0.02

0.07

0.07

 

NOx

0.14

0.25

0.08

0.14

 

 

 

 

 

dust

0.01

0.02

0.01

0.01

 

 

 

 

 

Total

0.17

0.30

0.17

0.31

0.02

0.02

0.07

0.07

Total

 

0.79

4.19

0.80

4.24

2.26

6.36

1.74

4.80

 aThe damage costs of the coal fuel cycle are based on emission data for a modern pulverized coal plant with a conversion efficiency of 44%. A main alternative in 2000 could be Coal Integrated Gasfication/Combined Cycle (CIG/CC) technology as demonstrated on a 275 MWe scale in Buggenum, the Netherlands. Performance data were given in table 2. However, the damage costs caused by emissions of NOx, SO2 and dust are of the same order of magnitude (0.99-5.79 mECU/kWh according to data of Hohmeyer and 1.68-4.90 mECU/kWh according to data from Dorland et al.11; which is slightly higher than the case presented here). Although further improvements are possible it is not likely that large differences between pulverized coal and gasification plants will occur. Major advantages of coal gasification are however also related to limited waste water production, which is not taken into account in this study.

bIt should be borne in mind that approximately half of the emissions to air of the biomass fuel cycle stem from crop production operations and transport. Here, these emissions are considered similar to emissions from the conversion unit. This is a simplification since the dispersion of these emissions is limited to a smaller area than emissions dispersed via a tall stack.

 

The CO2 emissions per kWh as produced in the fuel cycle of coal and biomass is calculated at 815 and 24 g/kWh respectively. Damage estimates of greenhouse gas emissions that could cause a climate change with severe consequences for nature and mankind, differ widely in literature. Here we will apply recent estimates from a major source: the Intergovernemental Panel on Climate Change.8 The IPCC summarizes the results of numerous studies on this topic and presents figures of about 1-25 ECU/ton CO2 (5-125 U$/ton C). The wideness of the ranges is mainly due to the different assumptions about the interest rates that should be applied to transfer future damage to present costs, differences in assumptions about future greenhouse gas concentrations in the atmosphere as projected in different scenarios and differences in the valuations of damage. Potential damage of climate change occurs on a global level and not only on a national scale (which is the level of investigation in this study). It can however be argued that the burden of potential damage cost by climatic change should be compensated in relation to the amount of greenhouse gases emitted. When those damage estimates are translated into external costs per kWh, this results in 0.02 - 0.59 mECU/kWh for the biomass fuel cycle and 0.83 - 20.73 mECU/kWh for the coal fuel cycle.

It should be kept in mind, however, that some authors suggest that higher damage costs of climate change are possible (see for example Sorensen68).

 4.4 External effects related to energy crop production

 Nitrogen leaching

In North Western Europe and in the Netherlands in particular, the abundant use of fertilizers and manure in agriculture has led to considerable environmental problems: nitrification of groundwater, saturation of soils with phosphate, leading to eutrophication and problems is meeting drinking water standards. Also, the application of phosphates has led to increased heavy metal flux to the soil. Energy farming with short rotation forestry and perennial grasses, however, requires less fertilizer than conventional agriculture.44,63 Data on nitrogen leaching occuring during the production of various crops and projections for short rotation coppice like Willow can be derived from Rijtema et al.47 With help of model calculations they consider the annual rainfall, precipitation excess, deposition of nitrogen by rainfall, denitrification rates and uptake efficiency of nutrients by various crops under Dutch conditions. This leads to estimates for the amount of fertilizer that leaches from the soil into ground and surface water. These estimates are summarized in table 9 for willow and three relevant food crops. The leaching of nitrogen relating to Willow cultivation can be about a factor 2-10 less than for food crops.47 Biewinga et al.65 confirm that leaching levels of Willow production are far lower compared to major food crops. They present values for the total nitrogen gift and expected leaching levels for various crops as well (see also table 9).

 A method of valuing some of these effects has been proposed by Ribera et al.45 The costs of the removal of nitrates in connection with production of drinking water is the basis of the economic valuation. However, the identification of causal relations between the production of a certain crop and the need to install denitrification processes is a difficult procedure and will for example depend on the degree of pollution of the groundwater from other sources, which are hard to quantify. Dispersion modelling and allocation of effects to other (agricultural) activities in a given area are too complex to handle. Therefore, to avoid the need for detailed modelling of hydrological aspects and leaching and the estimating of avoided costs, we apply an approach based on consumers Willingness To Pay for improved water quality with respect to nitrogen concentrations. Such data have been presented in a Swedish study.51 This study describes a WTP of 0.65-6.6 ECU per kg of N avoided in ground or surface water. It seems reasonable to transfer these data to the Dutch context, because of the similarities in environmental awareness and policies between the two countries. No data seem to be available about the willingness to pay to prevent the leaching of phosphate or other components and therefore no attempt has been made to value this aspect here.

 

Table 9. Calculated nitrogen leaching to groundwater and nitrogen application rates for SRC-Willow for some food crops grown under Dutch conditions.

  Crop

Soil

Precipitation excess according to Rijtema et al.47

(mm/yr)a

Nitrogen leaching according to Rijtema et al.47 (kg N/ha.yr)b

Nitrogen leaching according to Biewinga et al.65 (kg N/ha.yr)c

Total nitrogen gift by fertilizers according to Biewinga et al.65

(kg N/ha.yr)c

Willow

sand

248

16.0 (10.1-22.8)

 

 

 

clay

248

9.5 (6.0-13.6)

9

76

Cereals

sand

300

39.8

 

 

 

clay

300

29.2

47

280

Potatoes

sand

300

62.9

 

 

 

clay

300

46.1

42d

250d

Maize

sand

300

94.0

 

 

 

clay

300

68.9

59

309

 a Implies rainfall minus evapotranspiration by the crop.

b Atmospheric deposition of 35 kg N/ha/yr is included. This level is expected to drop in the future. Leaching data are average annual values; also a possible range is given. In practice variations between years might occur because of the 2 - 5 year rotation of SRC-Willow with fertilisation only in one or some of the years. More detailed data are not available at present. Average precipitation amounts to 750 mm.

c Data from Biewinga et al., are valid for conditions in the North of the Netherlands on clay soil.

d Values for production of beet, which are comparable to production of potatoes.

 

Table 10 presents the results of applying the WTP cost data to the leaching of nitrogen in the case of Willow. Two different cases are distinguished. The first case assumes that Willow production takes place on fallow or marginal land (which follows our reference system). Here leaching always results in damage (assuming that no leaching takes place from fallow land). For the sake of illustration, in the second case figures are given of avoided damage by reduced leaching when Willow replaces food crops.

The cost ranges found are obviously very wide. In the first place the fertilizer use for Willow might vary. Furthermore, the difference between minimum and maximum WTP data is a factor 10.

 Standards have been set by the EU and the Dutch government in order to prevent the exceeding of nitrate levels in groundwater. To meet health standards for groundwater (i.c. 50 mg nitrate/litre) the nitrogen gift should not exceed 170 kg N/ha.yr (or, for soils with a high adsorption capacity, 210 kg N/ha.yr).66 From the values given in table 9 it can be concluded that the nitrogen gifts for SRC-Willow are well below these standards. It is therefore doubtful whether the full cost range of WTP-data is valid for SRC-Willow production.

 

Table 10. Calculated external costs and potentially avoided damage of nitrogen leaching by SRC-Willow under Dutch conditions.

  

Total annual cost (MECU/yr)

Costs per kWh produced (mECU/kWh)

 

min

max

min

max

External costs nitrogen leaching

0.2

6.3

0.8

30

Avoided external costs nitrogen leaching if Willow would replace food crops

0.2

17

0.8

81

 

The Swedish WTP data are based on inquiries using the aforementioned health standards as a reference value. The study shows that the willingness to pay for measures that protect human health increases when (potential) health problems become more serious (and vice versa).51 This is however a qualitative result from the study and it is not known what the WTP is to reduce leaching to levels that would lower nitrate concentrations in groundwater further. It is therefore difficult to include this notion in a quantitative estimate of the damage costs of leaching caused by Willow production. However, the total nitrogen gift of SRC-Willow production remains well below health standards. We therefore suggest to use the lower value from the WTP cost range to obtain a damage estimate of nitrogen leaching of SRC-Willow production on fallow land. This discussion illustrates, however, that our understanding of the effects and seriousness of nitrogen leaching needs improvement and that the cost estimate of nitrogen leaching of SCR-Willow production should be seen as a first indication only.

 Agrochemical use

The agricultural use of pesticides can affect the health of people and the ground- and surface-water quality and consequently the flora and fauna. Specific effects strongly depend on the type of chemical, the quantities used and the method of application. However, it should be noted that not all effects causing damage to flora, fauna and human health - and the related dose-response curves - are well known or understood. Furthermore the potential number of dose-response curves is very large. Therefore, determining the external costs caused by the application of agrochemicals is very difficult if not impossible if one uses a damage function approach. Consequently, we will adopt another approach to estimate the external costs due to damage caused by agrochemicals based on shadow prices.

The National Environmental Policy Plan of the Netherlands states that a reduction of 50-70% in the use of agrochemicals in the Netherlands is desired in order to reach a more or less sustainable situation and prevent the exceeding of various haelth and environmental standards.67 This is a general figure and relates to the total use agrochemicals in Dutch agriculture. This reduction is expected to lead to the yield losses of 10-25%. As mentioned before, the projected losses correspond with a total economic value of 0.6-1.6 billion ECU per year in the Netherlands, according to Davidson et al.10 On basis of this estimate, they derive a shadow price for pesticides and herbicides of 44-110 ECU/kg active matter.( Using policy objectives as a basis for deriving external costs assumes that such objectives are based on 'optimal' decision making in economic terms. Although this may be unlikely it is argued here that other approaches to obtain damage cost estimates for agrochemical use are very hard, if not impossible, to implement with the current insights and data available (see also table 1)).

Table 11 gives a summary of agrochemical application rates of major food crops (data from LEI29) and a range of projected application rates for Willow.

 

Table 11. Rates of application of agrochemicals to food crops in the Netherlands and projections for SRC-Willow.

  Crop

Average application of chemicals

(kg active matter/ha.yr)

Cereals

4.2

Potatoes

9.2 - 17.5

Sugar beet

3.8

Maize

3.8

Various vegetables

2 - 16

Willow

0.4 - 2a

 aThe values for willow are projections, the higher figure has been derived from Zeijts et al.63, the lower one from Ranney, et al.44

 

Table 12 shows the consequences of applying these figures for the COE of the defined bio-energy system. The first case reflects the situation of the selected reference system in which willow production takes place on fallow land which results in damage; the costs of the damage are however highly uncertain. As an illustration the outcomes are shown if SRC Willow were to replace conventional food crops. The very wide range obtained (also with a possible zero effect) is caused by the wide range in avoided chemical use that can be achieved depending on the type of crop that is being replaced by Willow. If relatively large quantities of chemicals are applied to Willow and this crop replaces certain vegetables, there is no net benefit. If potatoes are replaced by Willow the benefit is very large.

 

Table 12. External costs and avoided damage relating to the use of agrochemicals for the defined bioenergy system.

  

Total annual costs

(MECU/yr)

Costs per kWh produced (mECU/kWh

 

min

max

min

max

External costs of agrochemical use

0.2

2.0

0.8

10

Avoided external costs of agrochemical use if Willow would replace food crops

0

18

0.0

84

 

Davidson et al.10 recognize that crop yield losses will increase stronger when agrochemical application rates are reduced further. Also, only limited yield losses will occur when reduction rates remain modest. Although this relation is hard to quantify for each crop under various conditions it is an important notion when the average application rates of chemicals for SRC-Willow and various food crops are considered (see table 11). When the application rates for the mentioned food crops are reduced by the mentioned 50-70% they are still all above the application rate for SRC-Willow as given by Ranney et al.44 (see table 11). It should be noted that the chemical application rate for Willow given in Zeijts et al.63 is an assumed level. The value of Ranney et al. is based on field tests with even higher yield levels than are assumed in Zeijts et al. We therefore consider the low value more realistic. When this all is kept in mind it is questionable whether the high shadow price for agrochemical use should be used for calculating the damage costs of SRC-Willow production; or even stronger, if any damage costs should be included at all, since SRC-Willow apparently meets the required environmental standards. Therefore, we suggest to use the lower value of the shadow price range to obtain an estimate for the external costs of agrochemical use of SRC-Willow production.

However, this discussion illustrates that our understanding of the effects and seriousness of agrochemical use for SRC-Willow production needs improvement and that the given cost estimate should be seen as a first indication only.

As a final remark; in this analysis no distinction is made between various categories of agrochemicals (A, B, and C, C being the most harmful to health and environment). In the case of willow production the types of chemicals that are expected to be used are generally A-type.63 So the overall avoided damage estimated by this method is fairly conservative.

Other aspects

Energy farming will also have an effect on soil quality, erosion, water use, nature and biodiversity. With respect to soil quality no attempt was made to valuate any external effect of biomass production, since it is an aspect which at present is hard to quantify. It relates to organic matter content, texture, presence of soil life and absence of diseases. Erosion is hardly a matter of importance in the Netherlands. Since the cover of multi-year rotation willow production is better than of most food crops, any effect that might occur will be very small in the Dutch context. Formation of root systems and less intensive management will most probably lead to improved soil quality when SRC is compared to production of food crops.33

Effects of SRC-Willow production on groundwater levels are unclear. Willow might give rise to somewhat higher water consumption than other crops35, which might contribute to the problem of dehydration. On the other hand Willow might allow higher groundwater tables than most food crops, which may counteract the effects of dehydration. Also, higher groundwater tables can have benefits in buffer zones of nature areas which could be expressed in avoided yield losses if food crops were cultivated in those areas. In the case of fallow land similar uncertainties occur, also influenced by site specific factors. Due to these uncertainties these effects are not evaluated further in this study.

The effects on biodiversity and nature by the introduction of SRC Willow are to a large extent unknown. Some benefits are expected since the crop provides a habitat for birds, insects, etc.19,48 The net effects will depend strongly on the previous land-use and the planning of energy crops in the landscape.1

Fundamental work with respect to the valuation of biodiversity and methodology development is essential to gain insight into this issue.22 Attempts to value biodiversity and nature have been made by several researchers including Groot20 and Markandaya et al.34 but are troubled by large uncertainties. The outcomes are very site specific and of less relevance to energy farming. Furthermore, lack of practical experience with large areas of energy crops is now a bottleneck for making an assessment of the impact on nature and biodiversity in various contexts.

Specifically in the Dutch context SRC might have a value by providing a corridor for certain species. This could save investment in landscape elements, such as described in Sijtsma et al.52,53 These elements should allow species to migrate from one nature area to another, which is the purpose of policy making with regard to the creation of a National Ecological Network in the Netherlands.32 Again, any benefit will be very site specific and valuation is not possible without further knowledge about whether SRC can actually serve as corridor for the desired species. Actual effects are however uncertain and will depend strongly on how energy farming is implemented in practice. Therefore, no attempt is made in this study to valuate such effects economically.

 

5. DISCUSSION

The results obtained and expressed in either costs or benefits per kWh are summarized in table 13. The figures 1 and 2 illustrate the comparison between coal and biomass including external costs and benefits, added together with the production costs of electricity. To obtain a minimum figure, the maximum benefits and minimum damage have been added up, whereas for the total maximum damage the minimum benefits per externality combined with maximum damage figures were taken together. This sum should however be seen as an indication of the external effects of the two fuel cycles and not as the external costs.

Uncertainties persist and assumptions had to be made in this study that can be disputed. However, the outcomes illustrate possible variations in the amount of external costs and benefits. The outcomes illustrate that the beneficial effects with respect to indirect GDP increments, and to a lesser extent employment, are considerable when biomass is compared with coal. This due mainly to the fact that coal is imported into the Netherlands and biomass is considered to be produced indigenously. However, the indirect effects are calculated for an ideal context in which production capacity and labour are under-utilized. If economic activity is already high, inflatory effects may occur, such as increasing costs of labour and goods. Such effects are not analyzed here and including them would require a completely different approach. However, since this study indicates that the indirect economic effects are important compared to other external costs and benefits, more detailed analysis is desired on this point. For example, the method applied to calculate multiplier effects does not account for a decrease in expenses throughout the economy, because expenditures are limited by the realization and operation of power generation capacity. Expenditures almost always lead to positive GDP effects with an I/O approach. To counteract this effect much more advanced economic models are required.

The potential damage caused by CO2 emissions is another aspect of this evaluation that causes a big difference between the external costs of coal and biomass. However, the costs of damage for CO2 are very uncertain and are strongly influenced by the interest rate and included effects, which results in a very wide cost range. Here, a cost range of 5-125 U$/tonne CO2) from the IPCC was used; the IPCC consulted and integrated the results of numerous sources with respect to potential damage of climage change and included various uncertainties in their cost range. However, it should be kept in mind that some authors suggest that higher damage costs of climate change are possible (see for example Sorensen68).

 

Table 13. Summary of results. Benefits are indicated by (-) since they lower the overall costs of the fuel cycle considered. Damages are indicated by (+) since they add to the overall costs.

 External effect

Value (mECU/kWh)

 

Biomass

Coal

* GDP-increment (benefit/loss)

(-) 6.0 - 15

(+) 6.9 - 8.4

* Employment effects (benefit)

(-) 0.8 - 4

(-) 0.3 - 1.5

* Emissions of SO2, NOx, dust, CO to air (damage)

I: Hohmeyer approach

II: Data from Dorland et al.

 

I: (+) 0.8 - 4.2

II: (+) 2.3 - 6.4

 

 

I: (+) 0.8 - 4.2

II: (+) 1.7 - 4.8

* CO2 emissions (damage)

(+) 0.0 - 0.6

(+) 0.8 - 21

* Potential damage from agrochemical use (damage)a

(+) 0.8 - (10)

n.a.

* Potential damage from nitrogen leaching (damage)a

(+) 0.8 - (30)

n.a.

Total external effecta

-15 - 2

7 - 24

Average COE

68

38

Total costsa

53 - 70

45 - 72

aNote that only the lower value for the damage costs for both nitrogen leaching and agrochemical use is included in the sum. The arguments to do so have been given in the text.

 

The external costs related to other air emissions (SO2, NOx, dust) are almost similar for coal and biomass based power generation and appear to be relatively low.

Damage or benefits resulting from (avoided) agrochemical use and nitrogen leaching are wide ranging. One reason is that the methods applied are fairly rough; for determining the damage caused by nitrogen leaching, Willingness To Pay data for the the improvement of groundwater quality were used. The minimum and maximum values vary by a factor 10. The other reason is that the actual impacts strongly depend on emissions from the energy farming system. These could vary with respect to fertilizer and pesticide use. In case SRC would replace food crops the ranges will widen further because of the possible avoided damage. The results indicate that the choice of the reference system has a substantial influence on this external cost category. In this study it is argued that the damage cost of nitrogen leaching and agrochemical use of SRC-Willow production are likely to be fairly low. However, the results are only indicative and a better understanding of these effects and related damage costs is desired.

Figure 1. Ranges of the valued external costs and benefits, compared with the average private costs of electricity production from biomass and coal. Emissions to air cover the emissions of SO2, NOx, dust and CO.
The case represents relatively low intensity energy farming on fallow land. In this case nitrogen leaching and agrochemical use will cause net environmental damages. These damages are counted together in the category 'emissions SRC'. Note that only one lower value for the damage costs for both nitrogen leaching and agrochemical use is included in the sum of the minimum and maximum total costs. The arguments to do so are given in the text.

Another reason for not considering the presented figures as 'final' figures is that a number of external effects have not been valued in this study. Aspects relating to the crop production system like soil erosion (or avoidance of erosion), water use (or the maintenance of higher ground water levels) and effects on nature and biodiversity (which could both be positive as well as negative) have not been quantified. Furthermore, a potentially important external effect which has not been valued is the occupational risks involved in crop production and transportation of biomass. Operations such as planting, harvesting, chipping and transportation of crops involve risks of accidents, injuries or casualties. It is argued in other studies, such as the US-EC fuel cycle studies and in particular in relation to coal mining, that the injuries and casualties can be a major part of the external costs of a fuel cycle.39 This aspect therefore requires further analysis.

The risk of injuries and casualties in energy farming are at present hardly known since there is no large scale commercial experience with these crops. Comparisons with forestry could be made, but might give a distorted view since forestry involves the logging of older, large trees and the use of equipment (such as chain saws) which is not used in the Willow production system considered here. In general energy farming, especially the production of SRC Willow and Miscanthus, will resemble current agriculture more closely than forestry and safety risks might therefore be small.

Figure 2. Comparison of the total cost of electricity including valued external effects (including uncertainties expressed by the minimum and maximum cost ranges).

 

Another set of external costs that have not been valued in this study relate to coal mining, transport and handling. Matters were simplified by focusing on impacts of the fuel cycles on a national scale; coal mining does not take place in the Netherlands.

Aspects and impacts of energy farming related to biodiversity, soil quality and hydrological aspects have only been discussed and no attempt has been made to value potential external effects. More substantial practical experience with energy farming and methodology development for internalizing such impacts is needed to allow a meaningful valuation.

This study has illustrated the importance of defining a reference system with which the studied system can be compared. When a bio-energy system is introduced it replaces not only fossil-fuel-based power generation but also other land-use. The extent to which damage or benefits occur depends partly on the alternatives investigated.58 An important example is the effect of an energy option on the GDP; coal based power generation will obtain a lower score on this beneficial effect in the Dutch context than biomass, mainly since coal needs to be imported. If coal were produced within the national economy the difference between the two cycles would be smaller or might even disappear. Another example is the use of land where energy farming is located. The alternative use of land determines whether an environmental benefit occurs (if it replaces food crops) or whether damage occurs (if it replaces fallow land).

For quantifying externalities more accurately further development of methodologies and detailed analysis of aspects such as dose response curves is needed. Furthermore, regular updating is required, since the context in which external effects occur can change: the performance of conversion technologies for all types of fuels is improving continuously. This reduces emission related environmental and health impacts, lowers private costs because of increased efficiency, etc. Emissions from coal plants for example have been reduced dramatically over the past decade. With respect to biomass this aspect is even more relevant since the SRC and BIG/CC technology are still at the demonstration phase and further development and optimization is expected. The speed at which such improvements take place will be determined mainly by research efforts and the experience that is gained by demonstration and commercial projects.

The context in which the externalities are determined also changes over time. Consequently, the value of certain effects, such as employment, may change over time as well. Such perspectives may also be influenced by the outcomes of externality analyses.

 

6. CONCLUSION

From this study the average private costs for biomass and coal based power generation are projected to be 68 and 38 mECU/kWh respectively in the year 2005. If the externalities which are quantified in this study are included, the cost range for bio-electricity amounts to 53-70 mECU/kWh and 45-72 mECU/kWh for coal. It is assumed that biomass production will take place on fallow land. Coal mining is excluded from the analysis. The order of magnitude of the external costs and benefits that have been found in this study, although uncertain, suggest that on a total cost basis bio-energy could even now be competitive with coal (see also figure 2).

Indirect economic effects (increment of Gross Domestic Product) and the difference in CO2 emissions are the most important distinguishing factors between coal and biomass in economic terms. Damage costs of other emissions to air (NOx, SO2, dust and CO) are of the same order of magnitude for both coal and biomass (coal mining excluded). Environmental impacts of energy farming depend strongly on the reference system and can both result in economic benefits or damage depending on the land-use that is replaced. Only a preliminary damage estimate has been given in this study, which suggests low damage costs, but a better understanding of various effects of nitrogen leaching and agrochemical use is desired.

It is difficult to integrate external costs into market prices in order to obtain an optimal allocation of resources, partly because of our lack of knowledge about these costs. Uncertainties are of such an order of magnitude and damage estimates are often so site-specific that it is impossible to internalize the external costs by a simple correction of the market prices.

Clearly, this analysis has not valuated all imaginable external effects of the fuel cycles considered. It has merely attempted to value a number of externalties of both coal and biomass fuel cycle, specifically for the Dutch context. A number of aspects cannot be valued at present because either the knowledge about physical effects is too limited or because the methodology to evaluate the effects is lacking. Because of this incomplete coverage the results should not be considered as the external costs of the biomass and coal fuel cycles considered. Furthermore, uncertainties remain e.g. with respect to the costs of climate change and numerous dose response relations. The aspects that can be valued, however, provide arguments for either supporting or discouraging a specific energy option. In this context the outcomes of this study plead for the support of bio-electricity production and/or taxation of coal based power generation.

 

Acknowledgements - The authors are grateful for the sponsoring of CEC DG XII within the framework of the APAS programme. The authors also want to express their appreciation to a number of people and institutions who provided information and commented on various aspects: Kees Dorland (IVM, Free University Amsterdam). Sake de Boer (CBS, Den Hague), Ekko van Ierland (Agricultural University of Wageningen), Bob Perlack and Virginia Tolbert (Oak Ridge National Laboratory, Oak Ridge, USA), Centre for Agriculture and Environment (CLM) and Erik van den Heuvel (NOVEM, Utrecht).

Rosa Maria Saez and Pedro Linares (CIEMAT, Madrid), John Flaherty and Lucy O'Shea (Trinity College, Dublin) and Jette Sontow (IER, Stuttgart) are thanked for their pleasant cooperation within the APAS project.

The Netherlands Organization for Scientific Reseach (NWO) is thanked for financially supporting a working visit to King's College London, London University. Sheila McNab is thanked for linguistic assistance.

 

7. REFERENCES

1. Bell, S., Forest Authority Edinburgh, Scotland, UK, Energy forest cultivation and the landscape. In: Biomass and Bioenergy Vol. 6, No. 1/2 pp. 53-61, 1994.

2. Blok, K., C.A. Hendriks, Elektriciteitsproduktietechnieken voor de komende twintig jaar: vergelijking van milieueffecten, Report no. W-90006, Department of Science, Technology and Society, Utrecht University, Utrecht, the Netherlands, 1989.

3. Broek, van den, R. A. Faaij, A.J.M. van Wijk, T. Kent, M. Bulfin, K. Healion, G. Blaney, Willow firing in retrofitted Irish power plants. Published in: Biomass and Bioenergy, Vol. 12, No. 2 pp. 75-90, 1997.

4. Cantor, R., L. Russell, US - EC Fuel Cycle Study: Background document to the approach and issues, Oak Ridge National Laboratory and Resources for the Future. Report no. ORNL/M-2500, Tennessee, 1992.

5. CBS (Netherlands Statistics Agency) De produktie-structuur van de Nederlandse Volkshuishouding; Deel XXI: Input-outputtabellen 1991: aanbod- en gebruikstabellen, Centraal Bureau voor de Statistiek, Voorburg/Heerlen, 1994.

6. CBS, Aanbod- en gebruikstabellen; Input-outputtabellen 1992, Centraal Bureau voor de Statistiek, Voorburg/Heerlen, 1995.

7. CBS Directe, indirecte en gecumuleerde arbeidsintensiteit per bedrijfsgroep; 1990 (Direct, indirect, and cumulated labor intensity by sector: 1990), CBS Statistics Netherlands: Sector National Accounts, The Hague, 1996.

8. Cline, W.R., A.N. Achanta, S. Fankhauser, R.K. Pachauri, D.P. Vellinga (1995). Costs of Climate Change: Damage and The Benefits of Control, IPPC, 2nd edited Draft, November 1995. D.W. Pearce, W.R. Cline, A.N. Achanta, S. Fankhauser, R.K. Pachauri, R.S.J. Tol, P. Vellinga, The social costs of climate change: greenhouse damage and the benefits of control. Chapter 6 of Climate Change 1995, economic and social dimensions of climate change; contribution of working group III to the second assessment report of the IPCC, edited by J.P. Bruce, H. Lee, E.F. Haites, Cambridge University Press, 1996.

9. Consonni, S., E. Larson, Biomass gasifier/aeroderivative gas turbine combined cycles, part B: performance calculations and economic assessment. Prepared for Cogen Turbo Power >94, The American Society of Mechanical Engineers, 8th congress & exposition on gas turbines and cogeneration and utility, industrial and independent power generation, Portland, Oregon, 25 - 27 October 1994.

10. Davidson, M., J. van Soest, G. de Wit, W. de Boo, Financial valuation of environmental damage in Dutch agriculture, an approach based on mitigation costs, Centrum voor Energiebesparing, Delft, February, 1996 (in Dutch).

11. Dorland, C., R. Hoefnagel, H.M.A. Jansen, R.S.J. Tol, The Dutch coal fuel cycle, Institute for Environmental Studies. Report prepared for CEC DG XII, Amsterdam, 1994.

12. Dorland, C., Personal communication, IVM, Amsterdam, the Netherlands, April 1996.

13. Dyson, T., Population and food, global trends and future prospects, Global Environmental Change Series, 1996.

14. Faaij, A., R. van Ree, L. Waldheim, E. Olsson, A. Oudhuis, A. van Wijk, C. Daey Ouwens, W. Turkenburg, Gasification of biomass wastes and residues for electricity production., Department of Science, Technology and Society, Utrecht University, Netherlands Energy Research Foundation (ECN) Termiska Processer AB, accepted for publication in Biomass and Bioenergy, May, 1997.

15. Faaij, A., B. Meuleman, Externalities of biomass based electricity production compared to coal based power generation, Study in the context of APAS project RENA-CT94-0060: "Incorporating externalities in the overall costs of bioenergy", Department of Science Technology and Society, Utrecht University, June 1996.

16. Faaij, A., Steetskamp, I., A. van Wijk, Exploration of the land potential for the production of biomass for energy in the Netherlands, Department of Science, Technology and Society, Utrecht University, submitted to Biomass and Bioenergy, May 1997.

17. Feenstra, F., J. Gigler, R. de Mol, A. Bosma, Logistics concerning the collection of biomass, IMAG-DLO, Wageningen, November 1994 (in Dutch).

18. Fockens, S., A.J.M. van Wijk , Ontwikkeling van de totale electriciteitsvoorziening in Nederland (developments of the total electricity supply in the Netherlands), Department of Science, technology and Society, Utrecht University, report no. 94055, Utrecht 1994 (in Dutch).

19. Goransson, G., Bird fauna of cultivated energy shrub forests at different heights, Department of Ecology, Lund University. In: Biomass and Bioenergy. Vol. 6 No. 1/2 pp. 49-52, 1994.

20. Groot de, R.S., Function of Nature, Wolters Noordhoff, Amsterdam, 1992.

21. Hall, D.O., F.Rosillo-Calle, R.H. Williams, J. Woods, Biomass for Energy; supply prospects. In: Renewable energy, source for fuels and electricity, Island Press, Washington DC, 1993.

22. Hein, L.G. , H.A.M. de Kruijf, Monetary and Non-monetary valuation of biodiversity for the countries of the sustainable development agreements: functions, values and techniques, Department of Science, Technology and Society, Utrecht University, Report no. 97002, Utrecht, January 1997.

23. Hoevenagel, R., The contingent valuation method; validity and applicability, Instituut voor milieuvraagstukken, Free University of Amsterdam, published in the report of the symposium on Monetary valuation of the environment, RMNO (Raad voor Natuur en Milieu) publication no. 99, The Hague, 1994.

24. Hohmeyer, O., Social Costs of Energy Consumption, Springer-Verlag, Heidelberg, Germany, 1988.

25. Hohmeyer, O. and R.L. Ottinger, External Environmental Costs of Electricity Power: Analysis and Internalization, Springer-Verlag, Heidelberg, Germany, 1991.

26. Hohmeyer, O., R.L. Otinger, Social costs of energy, Present status and future trends. Proceedings of an international conference held at Racine, Winsconsin, September 8-11,1992, Springer Verlag Berlin-Heidelberg 1994.

27. Hohmeyer, O., 'Renewables and the full costs of energy', Energy Policy, April (1992), pp. 365-375.

28. Ierland, E.C. van, W.J.M. Heijman, E.P. Kroese, E.A. Oskam, Foundations of macro-economics, Educatieve Partners Nederland B.V. Stenfert Kroese, ISBN 90-207-2370-7, Houten, the Netherlands, 1994.

29. LEI, Agricultural Economics Research Institute (LEI-DLO)/CBS, Agricultural statistics 1995, The Hague, July 1995.

30. Leal, J., P. Linares, R. Saez, Assessment of the externalities of biomass energy for electricity production, Centro de Investigacioes Energeticas, Medioambientales y Technologicas (CIEMAT), Madrid, March 1996.

31. Lysen, E.H., C. Daey Ouwens, M.J.G. van Onna, K. Blok, P.A. Okken, J. Goudriaan, The feasibility of biomass production for the Netherlands energy economy, Rapport nr. 71.140/0130, Nederlandse maatschappij voor energie en milieu (NOVEM), Utrecht, 1992.

32. LNV, Ministry of Agriculture, Nature and Fisheries, Report landscape, government decision Vision landscape, The Hague, October 1992 (in Dutch).

33. Makeschin, F., Effects of energy forestry on soils, Chair of Soil Science, University of Munchen. In: Biomass and Bioenergy Vol. 6, No. 1/2, pp. 63-79, 1994.

34. Markandaya, A., B. Rhodes, External costs of fuel cycles: an impact pathway approach, EC/US Fuel Cycle Study, Metroeconomica, 1992.

35. Nonhebel, S., Harvesting the sun's energy using agro-ecosystems, Department of Theoretical Production Ecology, Agricultural University Wageningen, Report NOP-MLK project 853117, Wageningen, September 1995.

36. National Technical University of Athens, External costs of fuel cycles - The case of biomass in Greece, Bioresource Technology Unit, Department of Chemical Engineering, Athens, Greece, June 1995.

37. OECD, OECD Environmental Data; Compendium 1993, OECD, Paris, 1994.

38. ORNL, Oak Ridge National Laboratory and Resources for the Future, Estimating fuel cycle externalities: analytical methods and issues. Report no. 2 on external costs and benefits of fuel cycles: a study by the US Department of Energy and the Commission of European Communities, November 1992.

39. ORNL, Oak Ridge National Laboratory, Estimating Externalities of Coal Fuel Cycles: estimation methods, impacts and values, Tennessee, 1994.

40. Pearce, D. Wittington, S. Georgiou, D. Moran, Economic values and the environment in the developing world. A report to the United Nations Environment Programme by The Centre for Social and Economic Research on the Global Environment (CSERGE), University College London, University of East Anglia UK and University of North Carolina, final draft, October 1994.

41. Perlack, R., J. Ranney, L. Wright, Environmental emissions and socio economic considerations in the production, storage and transportation of biomass energy feedstocks, Oak Ridge National Laboratory, Tennessee, USA, July 1992.

42. Perlack, R., Personal communication, Oak Ridge National Laboratory, Tennessee, April 1996.

43. Prognos, Die Externen Kosten der Energieversorgung, Schaffer-Poeschel Verlag, Stuttgart, Germany, 1992.

44. Ranney, J., L. Mann, Environmental considerations in energy crop production, Oak Ridge National Laboratory, Environmental Science Division. In: Biomass and Bioenergy, Vol. 6 no. 3 pp. 211-228, 1994.

45. Ribera, S. da Silva et al. Assessment of the externalities of biomass fuel cycles in Portugal, ExternE project Externalities of fuel cycles, Centro de Estudos em Economica da Energia, dos Transportes e do Ambiente, Lisboa, Portugal, 1996.

46. Rijk P., The costs and benefits of willow (Salix) in short rotation for niche energy markets in The Netherlands, Agricultural Economics Institute (LEI-DLO), The Hague, November 1994.

47. Rijtema, P., W. de Vries, Differences in precipitation excess and nitrogen leaching from agricultural lands and forest plantations, DLO Winand Staring Centre for Integrated Land, Soil and Water Research, Biomass and Bioenergy vol 6, no. 1/2 pp.103-113, 1994.

48. Sage, R.B., P.A. Robertson, Wildlife and game potential of short rotation coppice in the U.K., The Game Conservancy Trust in: Biomass and Bioenergy. Vol. 6, no 1/2 pp. 41-4, 1994.

49. SEP, Elektriciteitsplan 1993-2002, Dutch Electricity Generating Board (SEP) Arnhem, 1992 (in Dutch).

50. SEP, Electricity in the Netherlands: year (Elektriciteit in Nederland), Dutch Electricity Generating Board (SEP), Arnhem, 1995 (in Dutch).

51. Silvander, U., The willingness to pay for angling and ground water in Sweden. Dissertations no. 2. Swedish University of Agricultural Sciences, Department of Economics, Uppsala, Sweden, 1991.

52. Sijtsma, F.J., D. Strijker, G.J. Rotmensen, Effect analysis of the Ecological Main Structure, part I main report, Stichting Ruimtelijke Economie, University of Groningen, 1995.

53. Sijtsma, F.J., D. Strijker, G.J. Rotmensen, Effect analysis of the Ecological Main Structure, part II value of nature, Stichting Ruimtelijke Economie, University of Groningen, 1995.

54. Swezey, B.G., K.L. Porter, J.S. Feher, The potential impact of externalities considerations on the market for biomass power technologies, National Renewable Energy Laboratory. In: Biomass and Bioenergy, Vol. 8, No. 4 pp. 207-220, 1995.

55. Tromp, Personal communication, Dutch Electricity Generating Board (SEP), Arnhem, May 1996.

56. Turnhollow, A., The economics of energy crop production, Oak Ridge National Laboratory, Environmental Sciences Division. In: Biomass and Bioenergy. Vol 6. no.3 pp. 211-228, 1994.

57. Veen, A., van der, E. Wierstra, P Geurts, The contingent valuation method and monetary valuation of the environment, published in the report of the symposium on Monetary valuation of the environment, RMNO (Raad voor Natuur en Milieu) publication no. 99, The Hague, 1994.

58. Walsh, P., A. Matthews, J. Flaherty, L. O'Shea, The macro implications of biomass as an alternative land use, Department of Economics, Trinity College, University of Dublin, May, 1996.

59. Wicke, L., Die Ökologischen Milliarden; Das Kostet die Zerstörte - so können wir sie retten, Münich, Germany, 1986.

60. Wijk van, A., W. Turkenburg, The value of wind energy, presented at BWEA '91, Department of Science, Technology and Society, Utrecht University, 1991.

61. Wijk van A., De Nederlandse Elektriciteitsvoorziening 1981-2002 Brandstofinzet en emissies (the Dutch electricity supply 1981-2002. Fuel inputs and emissions), Department of Science, Technology and Society, Utrecht University, Utrecht, 1992 (in Dutch).

62. Williams, R.H., E.D. Larson, Advanced gasification based biomass power generation. In: J.B. Johansson, H. Kelly, A.K.N. Reddy, R.H. Williams, Renewable Energy, Island Press, Washington DC, 1993.

63. Zeijts van, H., E. Oosterveld, E. Timmerman, Can agriculture provide clean energy? Evaluation of the sustainability of energy crops. Centre for Agriculture and the Environment (CLM), Utrecht, August 1994.

64. Munasinghe, M., The economists' approach to sustainable development; In: Environmentally Sustainable Development, Occasional Paper Series No. 2, The World Bank, Washington, 1994.

65. Biewinga, E.E., G. van der Bijl, Sustainability of energy crops in Europe, a methodology developed and applied, Centre for Agriculture and Environment, Utrecht, November 1995.

66. Ministry of Agriculture, Nature and Fisheries, Structure Document Agriculture, The Hague, 1990.

67. Ministry of Housing, Physical Planning and Environment, National Environmental Policy Plan II (NMP II), The Hague, 1993.

68. Sorensen, B., Externality estimation of greenhouse warming impacts, Roskilde University Institute 2, Energy and Environment Group, Roskilde Denmark, 1996.


N


Last update:
For any question or suggestion, please feel free to contact the Webmaster.